Analysis

Climate change could trigger debt crises, with adaptation providing only partial relief

Climate change is likely to significantly undermine sovereign debt sustainability, especially from the mid-2040s

Publishing date
16 April 2025
Stavros 160425

For many countries, climate change is likely to lower growth and increase the frequency of natural disasters. This will strain public finances from both the revenue and expenditure sides, which will in turn lead to fears of defaults and thus raise government borrowing costs, adding more strain (Dibley et al2021; Zenios, 2022). How likely is it that these feedback loops will lead some countries to default? Which countries are particularly at risk?

One way to answer these questions is to overlay climate scenarios onto debt sustainability analysis, which is used to assess how well-equipped sovereigns are to meet their liabilities. Calcaterra et al (2025) developed a model to do just this and here we show results from the model for Australia, Brazil, Italy, India, Finland and Tanzania.

For climate-economy scenarios, Calcaterra et al (2025) used the RICE50+ model (Gazzotti et al, 2021). Based on Nordhaus (1993), RICE50+ projects economic growth under different shared socioeconomic pathways (SSPs) and representative concentration pathways (RCPs), which describe future greenhouse gas emission trends, and based on different assumptions about how rising emissions will affect growth.

Two possible future pathways from the United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change are known as SSP2-RCP4.5 and SSP3-RCP7.0 (Nakicenovic et al, 2014). SSP2-RCP4.5 assumes that socioeconomic trends will follow historical patterns and that the impact of greenhouse gas emissions will be moderate. SSP3-RCP7.0 assumes that there will be regional rivalry international fragmentation as observed in current geopolitical conflicts combined with relatively high greenhouse gas emissions, leading to a median temperature rise of up to about 3.4 degrees Celsius by 2100. For each scenario, GDP projections are derived under two different assumptions: that emissions will damage output to a small or large extent 1 The small impact on output assumption is based on Kalkuhl and Wenz (2020) and the large impact on Burke et al (2015). These functions span the estimates of existing climate-economy models, with the large-impact projections remarkably close to estimates by Kotz et al (2024). . Table 1 shows how GDP will be impacted by climate damages in the two socioeconomic and warming scenarios and the two output impact assumptions.

Table 1: Changes to GDP (%) due to climate change, to the end of the century, selected countries

 

Small impact

 

Large impact

Narrative scenario

Country

2030

2050

2070

2100

Avg.

 

2030

2050

2070

2100

Avg.

 

 

World

-1

-3

-4

-5

-3

 

-4

-18

-35

-60

-26

 

 

Australia

0

-2

-3

-5

-2

 

-2

-10

-23

-45

-19

 

SSP2-RCP4.5

Brazil

-1

-3

-5

-7

-4

 

-4

-24

-49

-77

-38

 

 

Finland

0

0

0

0

0

 

+8

+56

+138

+155

+92

 

 

India

-1

-4

-7

-10

-5

 

-4

-24

-53

-83

-41

 

 

Italy

0

-2

-3

-3

-2

 

-1

-4

-10

-22

-9

 

 

Tanzania

-1

-3

-5

-7

-4

 

-3

-23

-47

-76

-37

 

 

 

World

 

-1

 

-3

 

-5

 

-9

 

-4

 

 

-4

 

-17

 

-37

 

-68

 

-28

 

 

Australia

0

-2

-4

-8

-4

 

-2

-11

-27

-56

-22

 

SSP3-RCP7.0

Brazil

-1

-3

-7

-12

-6

 

-5

-26

-52

-84

-41

 

 

Finland

0

0

0

-1

0

 

+8

+57

+139

+156

+93

 

 

India

0

-3

-8

-16

-6

 

-4

-23

-53

-88

-41

 

 

Italy

0

-2

-4

-7

-3

 

-1

-4

-12

-32

-11

 

 

Tanzania

-1

-3

-7

-12

-6

 

-4

-25

-52

-84

-41

 

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025). Note: changes are calculated assuming no adaptation to climate change.

Table 1 shows that in both narrative scenarios, the overall GDP loss up to the end of the century would be low if the impact of climate change on output is small. However, if the impact is large (as is predicted by current climate models), GDP losses could be extremely high, averaging about -28 percent for the world from 2030 to 2100 (though differences between the losses in different countries would be substantial). The impacts are larger for SSP3 than SSP2. 

This approach can also be used to compute the optimal level of climate adaptation policies and their impact on GDP, distinguishing between reactive adaptation (eg disaster relief) and proactive adaptation (eg building coastal protection infrastructure). It can also factor in adaptive capacity linked to a countrys level of development and R&D investments (eg early warning systems). Figure 1 shows how adaptation measures increase output relative to the no-adaptation baseline, assuming large impacts. Estimates range from little difference (Italy), to a 15 percent increase in GDP relative to the climate-damaged level (Brazil). The model also provides estimates of adaptation costs, ranging from 0.12 percent to 2.46 percent of GDP, evenly split between proactive and reactive adaptation and adaptive capacity (see the appendix). 

Figure 1: Reduced climate damages due to adaptation, selected countries

q

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025). Note: Projections assume large impacts from climate change.

 

Borrowing costs and future borrowing needs for each of the output paths generated by the RICE50+ model are based on a debt sustainability model (Zenios et al, 2021). This makes different assumptions of who will pay the costs of the adaptation investment: the private sector entirely (no fiscal cost), the public sector entirely, or a combination. On this basis, we generated distributions (fan charts) for future debt.

Figure 2 shows the distributions associated with the SSP2-RCP4.5 and SSP3-RCP7.0 scenarios for both small climate damages and large climate damages (without any climate adaptation) and compares each to a benchmark in which climate damages are assumed to be zero (grey fan charts) 2 For the benchmark, we use GDP projections from RICE50+ without climate effects and the World Economic Outlook (WEO) primary balance projections or, when the debt dynamics under the WEO projections would be unsustainable, we estimate the debt-stabilising primary balance (Calcaterra et al, 2025). . As expected, the small and large climate damage scenarios adversely affect countries debt trajectories in most cases, with the 75th percentile shifting upwards. Nevertheless, the 75th percentile remains downward sloping in the small climate damage scenarios, except for Brazil and India. In the large climate impacts scenario, debt becomes explosive at the 75th percentile for all countries except Finland. It is also explosive at the median percentile for all countries except Finland and Italy.

Figure 2: Climate-change impact on country debts in the long run

A: Small climate damages  

2a


B: Large climate damages

2b


Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025). Note: the debt ratio (% of GDP) until the end of the century with small and large climate damage is overlaid on the debt ratios without climate effects (zero-damage, grey-shaded). Lines indicate the median and interquartile ranges.

The next step is to compute the long-term primary fiscal balances (the excess of revenues over non-interest expenditures) that would stabilise the climate-impacted trajectories with 75 percent probability, assuming that climate damage is zero, small or large. We consider debt-stabilising primary surpluses of up to 3 percent of GDP to be feasible (based on Eichengreen and Panizza, 2016). Table 2 shows the results, with the first column denoting historical averages.

Table 2: Primary balance to stabilise sovereign debt, %

 

 

 

      SSP2-CP4.5

 

 

      SSP3-RCP7.0

 

 

Country

Hist.

 

Zero

Small

Large

 

 

Zero

Small

Large

 

Australia

-1.2

 

-1.6

-1.6

-1.0

 

 

-1.6

-1.6

-0.2

 

 

Brazil

0.7

 

1.4

1.6

2.8

 

 

2.4

2.6

4.0

 

 

Finland

0.2

 

-1.2

-1.2

-1.0

 

 

-1.2

-1.2

-1.0

 

 

India

-4.0

 

0.2

0.4

2.2

 

 

1.2

1.4

3.8

 

 

Italy

1.0

 

0.6

0.8

1.6

 

 

1.6

2.2

3.4

 

 

Tanzania

-0.7

 

-0.2

-0.2

0.4

 

 

-0.2

-0.2

0.8

 

 

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025). 

As one would expect from Figure 2, climate damages could have a major impact on the debt-stabilising primary balance, particularly in the large-damages scenario. However, primary balances would generally remain below the 3 percent threshold. The exceptions are Brazil, India, and Italy in the large-damages scenario, suggesting that at least without effective adaptation climate change could lead to unsustainable debt in these countries.

We finally ask how these results change if adaptation is taken into account, based on different assumptions about who pays the adaptation costs. Figure 3 shows the range of end-of-century debt ratios with different adaptation policies for both climate narratives. The shaded area displays the interquartile range of debt ratios there is a U-shaped relationship between end-of-the-century debt and public investment in adaptation. Fully private adaptation reduces debt ratios compared to no adaptation, although only marginally for some countries. Government spending on reactive adaptation can reduce debt ratios, but the benefits do not cover the costs if the government fully funds adaptation.

The double arrows on top of the whiskers in Figure 3 denote the direction of the 75th percentile of the debt trajectory. Horizontal means the debt is stable; upward pointing means the debt is growing. For Australia and Brazil, privately funded adaptation would stabilise the debt; in all other cases, it would lower debt ratios, but debts would remain upward-sloping. This raises the question of how much adaptation is needed to lower the debt-stabilising primary balance and if this is below the 3 percent threshold.

Figure 3: Effects of adaptation scenarios on debt ratios

3

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025).

Table 3 shows stabilising primary balances with and without adaptation in the worst-case scenario: SSP3-RCP7.0 scenario with large climate damages (when adaptation is most beneficial). Compared to the stabilising balance under identical climate conditions but no adaptation costs, the stabilising balance with adaptation costs is lower. For Italy, the required primary balance would be reduced from 3.4 percent to 3.0 percent, which can be considered feasible, but for Brazil and India it would remain above the 3 percent threshold.

Table 3: Primary balance to stabilise sovereign debt with adaptation

 

 

 

Without adaptation

With adaptation

 

 

Australia

 

 

-0.2

-0.4

 

 

Brazil

 

 

4.0

3.7

 

 

Finland

 

 

-1.0

NA

 

 

India

 

 

3.8

3.6

 

 

Italy

 

 

3.4

3.0

 

 

Tanzania

 

 

0.8

0.6

 

 

               

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025). Note: adaptation calculation is not done for Finland because it stands to benefit economically in the climate-change scenarios.

Public financing of reactive adaptation with the rest of the adaptation taken on by the private sector can positively affect debt sustainability for debt that covers its cost. However, adaptation does not necessarily render debt sustainable. There is a broad consensus that significant adaptation expenditures will have to be borne by governments, but our tests highlight the limits of adaptation in averting potential debt crises precipitated by climate change.

Conclusion

Climate change is likely to have significant adverse effects on debt sustainability. The magnitude of the impact is subject to deep uncertainty. It can be a few percentage points or extremely large, potentially precipitating debt crises, depending on the scenario. The effects would be noticeable from the mid-2040s, potentially becoming substantial from mid-century.

Maintaining debt sustainability is possible with additional fiscal effort. However, the required debt-stabilising primary balances appear challenging under extreme climate narratives involving large-scale damages and may not be feasible for all countries. Climate adaptation can help mitigate the adverse effects of debt but is not a panacea. Governments would be able to finance only up to one-third of adaptation costs and still break even. The adage that there can be no public-finance sustainability without environmental sustainability is corroborated.

References

Burke, M., S.M. Hsiang and E. Miguel (2015) Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic production, Nature 527: 235239, available at 

Calcaterra, M., A. Consiglio, V. Martorana, M. Tavoni and S.A. Zenios (2025) Sovereigns on thinning ice: debt sustainability, climate impacts and adaptation, Working Paper, Bruegel, forthcoming

Nakicenovic, N., R. Lempert, A.C. Janetos (eds) (2014) Special Issue: A Framework for the Development of New Socio-economic Scenarios for Climate Change Research, Climatic Change 122(3), available at 

Dibley, A., T. Wetzer and C. Hepburn (2021) National COVID debts: climate change imperils countries ability to repay, Nature 592: 184187, available at 

Eichengreen, B. and U. Panizza (2016) A surplus of ambition: can Europe rely on large primary surpluses to solve its debt problem? Economic Policy 31(85): 549, available at 

Gazotti, P., J. Emmerling, G. Marangoni, A. Castelletti, K.I. van der Wijst, A. Hof and M. Tavoni (2021) Persistent inequality in economically optimal climate policies, Nature Communications 12: 3421, available at 

Kalkuhl, M. and L. Wenz (2020) The impact of climate conditions on economic pro- duction. Evidence from a global panel of regions, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 103: 102360, available at 

Kotz, M., A. Levermann and L. Wenz (2024) The economic commitment of climate change, Nature 628: 551557, available at 

Nordhaus, W.D. (1993) Rolling the DICE: an optimal transition path for controlling greenhouse gases, Resource and Energy Economics, 15(1): 2750, available at 

Zenios, S.A., A. Consiglio, M. Athanasopoulou, E. Moshammer, A.G. Gonzalez and A. Erce (2021) Risk Management for Sustainable Sovereign Debt Financing, Operations Research 69: 755773, available at 

Zenios, S.A. (2022) The risks from climate change to sovereign debt, Climatic Change, 172: 30, available at 

Appendix: costs of proactive and reactive adaptation and adaptive capacity (% of GDP) up to the end of the century, selected countries

SSP2-RCP4.5                                                             SSP3-RCP7.0

Country

All

Proactive

Reactive

Capacity

 

All

Proactive

Reactive

Capacity

 

Australia

0.84

0.51

0.32

0.02

 

0.90

0.57

0.31

0.02

 

Brazil

2.46

0.77

0.47

1.22

 

2.24

0.93

0.46

0.85

 

India

1.32

0.49

0.62

0.20

 

0.96

0.37

0.47

0.12

 

Italy

0.12

0.08

0.02

0.01

 

0.16

0.11

0.03

0.02

 

Tanzania

0.38

0.18

0.15

0.05

 

0.29

0.15

0.10

0.05

 

Source: Bruegel based on Calcaterra et al (2025).

 

About the authors

  • Matteo Calcaterra

  • Andrea Consiglio

    Andrea Consiglio is a Professor of Quantitative Methods for Economics and Finance at the University of Palermo. He holds a PhD in Applied Mathematics to Finance and Economics and has extensive experience in mathematical finance, risk management, and sovereign debt sustainability. His research interests span from option pricing and portfolio management to stochastic programming and artificial markets. Prof. Consiglio has collaborated with prominent international institutions, including the Bank for International Settlements, the European Stability Mechanism, and the Bank of Finland. He is an Associate Editor for Optimization and Engineering and Risks, and the author of numerous peer-reviewed articles and books on financial optimization and risk management.

  • Vincenzo Martorana

  • Massimo Tavoni

    Massimo Tavoni is full professor of climate change economics at Politecnico di Milano, and director of the European Institute on the Economy and the Environment (EIEE) at CMCC. He has been fellow at the Center for Advanced Studied in Behavioural Sciences at Stanford University, and post doctoral fellow at Princeton University. He has been a lead author of the IPCC (5th and 6th reports), and co-directs of the International Energy Workshop. He has been awarded two grants from the European Research Council (ERC).

  • Stavros Zenios

    Stavros Zenios is a Cypriot citizen with a long career in the USA. His current research focuses on sovereign debt issues, especially in relation to the challenges posed by climate change and political risks. He is working on the development of stochastic dynamic models for debt sustainability analysis and risk management for sovereigns, on sovereign contingent debt, and on the asset pricing effects of political risks. He has published more than 150 articles in leading academic journals, encyclopedias, and handbooks, and edited numerous collected works. He regularly appears on national media discussing issues relating to the economy, transparency and corruption and is consulted by the international press on Eurozone crisis issues. He was Vice chairman of the Cyprus Council of Economic Advisors and served on the Board of the Central Bank of Cyprus.  He served two terms as President of UNICA-Universities of European Capitals and two terms as Rector of the University of Cyprus.

    He is a Professor of Operations Management and Finance at Durham University (UK), on sabbatical leave from the University of Cyprus, where he has been a Professor of Finance and Management Science since 1991. Prior to that, he was a tenured faculty member at the Wharton School, USA, where he remains a Senior fellow of the Financial Institutions Center.

Related content